FREE BOOKS

Author's List




PREV.   NEXT  
|<   118   119   120   121   122   123   124   125   126   127   128   129   130   131   132   133   134   135   136   137   138   139   140   141   142  
143   144   145   146   147   148   149   150   151   152   153   154   155   156   157   158   159   160   161   162   163   164   165   166   167   >>   >|  
ay grant the use of a house while retaining the ownership. For this reason a man may lawfully make a charge for the use of his house, and, besides this, revendicate the house from the person to whom he has granted its use, as happens in renting and letting a house. 'But money, according to the philosopher,[1] was invented chiefly for the purpose of exchange; and consequently the proper and principal use of money is its consumption or alienation, whereby it is sunk in exchange. Hence it is by its very nature unlawful to take payment for the use of money lent, which payment is known as usury; and, just as a man is bound to restore other ill-gotten goods, so he is bound to restore the money which he has taken in usury.'[2] [Footnote 1: _Eth._ v. _Pol_. 1.] [Footnote 2: II. ii. 78, 1.] The essential thing to notice in this explanation is that the contract of _mutuum_ is shown to be a sale. The distinction between things which are consumed in use (_res fungibiles_), and which are not consumed in use (_res non fungibiles_) was familiar to the civil lawyers; but what they had never perceived was precisely what Aquinas perceived, namely, that the loan of a fungible thing was in fact not a loan at all, but a sale, for the simple reason that the ownership in the thing passed. Once the transaction had been shown to be a sale, the principle of justice to be applied to it became obvious. As we have seen above, in treating of sales, the essential basis of justice in exchange was the observance of _aequalitas_ between buyer and seller--in other words, the fixing of a just price. The contract of _mutuum_, however, was nothing else than a sale of fungibles, and therefore the just price in such a contract was the return of fungibles of the same value as those lent. If the particular fungible sold happened to be money, the estimation of the just price was a simple matter--it was the return of an amount of money of equal value. As money happened to be the universal measure of value, this simply meant the return of the same amount of money. Those who maintained that something additional might be claimed for the use of the money lost sight of the fact that the money was incapable of being used apart from its being consumed.[1] To ask for payment for the sale of a thing which not only did not exist, but which was quite incapable of existence, was clearly to ask for something for nothing--which obviously offended against the first prin
PREV.   NEXT  
|<   118   119   120   121   122   123   124   125   126   127   128   129   130   131   132   133   134   135   136   137   138   139   140   141   142  
143   144   145   146   147   148   149   150   151   152   153   154   155   156   157   158   159   160   161   162   163   164   165   166   167   >>   >|  



Top keywords:

return

 

consumed

 

exchange

 
contract
 
payment
 

simple

 

incapable

 

essential

 
Footnote
 

mutuum


restore
 

perceived

 

fungible

 

fungibles

 

fungibiles

 

happened

 

amount

 

justice

 
reason
 

ownership


lawfully

 

estimation

 

treating

 

observance

 

aequalitas

 

charge

 

matter

 

fixing

 

seller

 

existence


offended

 

simply

 
measure
 

universal

 

maintained

 

claimed

 

retaining

 
additional
 
alienation
 

notice


explanation

 
consumption
 

chiefly

 

distinction

 
purpose
 
principal
 

proper

 

nature

 

unlawful

 

things