FREE BOOKS

Author's List




PREV.   NEXT  
|<   127   128   129   130   131   132   133   134   135   136   137   138   139   140   141   142   143   144   145   146   147   148   149   150   151  
152   153   154   155   156   157   158   159   160   161   162   163   164   165   166   167   168   169   170   171   172   >>  
actually made by commerce or in exchange';[1] and Ambrosius de Vignate explains that compensation must only be made for 'the time and just _interesse_ of the lost gain, which must be certain and proximate.'[2] [Footnote 1: _Eth._, iv. 6.] [Footnote 2: _De Usuris_, c. 10.] There was another title on account of which more than the amount of the loan could be recovered, namely, _periculum sortis_. In one sense it was a contradiction in terms to speak of the element of risk in connection with usury, because from its very definition usury was gain without risk as opposed to profit from a trading partnership, which, as we shall see presently, consisted of gain coupled with the risk of loss. It could not be lost sight of, however, that in fact there might be a risk of the loan not being repaid through the insolvency of the borrower, or some other cause, and the question arose whether the lender could justly claim any compensation for the undertaking of this risk. 'Regarded as an extrinsic title, risk of losing the principal is connected with the contract of _mutuum_, and entitles the lender to some compensation for running the risk of losing his capital in order to oblige a possibly insolvent debtor. The greater the danger of insolvency, the greater naturally would be the charge. The contract was indifferent to the object of the loan; it mattered not whether it was intended for commerce or consumption; it was no less indifferent to profit on the part of the borrower; it took account simply of the latter's ability to pay, and made its charge accordingly. It resembled consequently the contracts made by insurance companies, wherein there is a readiness to risk the capital sum for a certain rate of payment; the only difference was that the probabilities charged for were not so much the likelihood of having to pay, as the likelihood of not receiving back.'[1] [Footnote 1: Cleary, _op. cit._, p. 115.] We have referred above, when dealing with the legitimacy of commercial profits, to the difficulty which was felt in admitting the justice of compensation for risk, on account of the Gregorian Decretal on the subject. The same decree gave rise to the same difficulty in connection with the justification of a recompense for _periculum sortis_. There was a serious dispute about the actual wording of the decree, and even those who agreed as to its wording differed as to its interpretation.[1] The justice of the title was, howeve
PREV.   NEXT  
|<   127   128   129   130   131   132   133   134   135   136   137   138   139   140   141   142   143   144   145   146   147   148   149   150   151  
152   153   154   155   156   157   158   159   160   161   162   163   164   165   166   167   168   169   170   171   172   >>  



Top keywords:

compensation

 

Footnote

 

account

 
profit
 

connection

 
likelihood
 

indifferent

 

difficulty

 

justice

 
wording

decree

 

charge

 

greater

 

borrower

 

insolvency

 

lender

 

losing

 
capital
 
contract
 
commerce

periculum

 

sortis

 
payment
 

readiness

 

difference

 

probabilities

 

receiving

 
mattered
 

charged

 

companies


insurance

 

simply

 

consumption

 

ability

 

intended

 

contracts

 

resembled

 
Vignate
 

dispute

 
recompense

justification

 

subject

 

actual

 

differed

 

interpretation

 

howeve

 

agreed

 

Decretal

 

Gregorian

 

referred