FREE BOOKS

Author's List




PREV.   NEXT  
|<   129   130   131   132   133   134   135   136   137   138   139   140   141   142   143   144   145   146   147   148   149   150   151   152   153  
154   155   156   157   158   159   160   161   162   163   164   165   166   167   168   169   170   171   172   >>  
l to induce a man to sin, yet it is lawful to make use of another's sin for a good end, since even God uses all sin for some good, since He draws some good from every evil.... Accordingly it is by no means lawful to induce a man to lend under a condition of usury; yet it is lawful to borrow for usury from a man who is ready to do so, and is a usurer by profession, provided that the borrower have a good end in view, such as the relief of his own or another's need.... He who borrows for usury does not consent to the usurer's sin, but makes use of it. Nor is it the usurer's acceptance of usury that pleases him, but his lending, which is good.'[1] [Footnote 1: II. ii. 78, 4.] We should mention here the _montes pietatis_, which occupied a prominent place among the credit-giving agencies of the later Middle Ages, although it is difficult to say whether their methods were examples of or exceptions to the doctrines forbidding usury. These institutions were formed on the model of the _montes profani_, the system of public debt resorted to by many Italian States. Starting in the middle of the twelfth century,[1] the Italian States had recourse to forced loans in order to raise reserves for extraordinary necessities, and, in order to prevent the growth of disaffection among the citizens, an annual percentage on such loans was paid. A fund raised by such means was generally called a _mons_ or heap. The propriety of the payment of this percentage was warmly contested during the fourteenth and fifteenth centuries--the Dominicans and Franciscans defending it, and the Augustinians attacking it. But its justification was not difficult. In the first place, the loans were generally, if not universally, forced, and therefore the payment of interest on them was purely voluntary. As we have seen, Aquinas was quite clear as to the lawfulness of such a voluntary payment. In the second place, the lenders were almost invariably members of the trading community, who were the very people in whose favour a recompense for _lucrum cessans_ would be allowed.[2] Laurentius de Rodulphis argued in favour of the justice of these State loans, and contended that the bondholders were entitled to sell their rights, but advised good Christians to abstain from the practice of a right about the justice of which theologians were in such disagreement[3]; and Antoninus of Florence, who was in general so strict on the subject of usury, took the same view.[4]
PREV.   NEXT  
|<   129   130   131   132   133   134   135   136   137   138   139   140   141   142   143   144   145   146   147   148   149   150   151   152   153  
154   155   156   157   158   159   160   161   162   163   164   165   166   167   168   169   170   171   172   >>  



Top keywords:

lawful

 

payment

 

usurer

 

difficult

 

justice

 

States

 

generally

 
favour
 

Italian

 

percentage


induce

 

voluntary

 

forced

 

montes

 

purely

 

universally

 
interest
 

fourteenth

 

propriety

 

warmly


contested

 

raised

 

called

 

Aquinas

 

Augustinians

 

attacking

 
defending
 

Franciscans

 

fifteenth

 

centuries


Dominicans

 

justification

 

advised

 

Christians

 

abstain

 

practice

 

rights

 

contended

 
bondholders
 

entitled


strict
 
subject
 

general

 
Florence
 

theologians

 
disagreement
 

Antoninus

 

argued

 

members

 

trading