FREE BOOKS

Author's List




PREV.   NEXT  
|<   107   108   109   110   111   112   113   114   115   116   117   118   119   120   121   122   123   124   125   126   127   128   129   130   131  
132   133   134   135   136   137   138   139   140   141   142   143   144   145   146   147   148   149   150   151   152   153   154   155   156   >>   >|  
his maximum rate--the _Centesima_--remained in operation until the time of Justinian.[2] Justinian, who was under the influence of Christian teaching, and who might therefore be expected to have regarded usury with unfavourable eyes, fixed the following maximum rates of interest--maritime loans twelve per cent.; loans to ordinary persons, not in business, six per cent.; loans to high personages (_illustres_) and agriculturists, four per cent.[3] [Footnote 1: Cleary, _The Church and Usury_, p. 21.] [Footnote 2: Hunter, _Roman Law_, pp. 652-53; Cleary, _op. cit._, pp. 22-6; Roscher, _Political Economy_, s. 90.] [Footnote 3: _Code_ 4, 32, 26, 1.] While the taking of interest was thus approved or tolerated by Greek and Roman law, it was at the same time reprobated by the philosophers of both countries. Plato objects to usury because it tends to set one class, the poor or the borrowers, against another, the rich or the lenders; and goes so far as to make it wrong for the borrower to repay either the principal or interest of his debt. He further considers that the profession of the usurer is to be despised, as it is an illiberal and debasing way of making money.[1] While Plato therefore disapproves in no ambiguous words of usury, he does not develop the philosophical bases of his objection, but is content to condemn it rather for its probable ill effects than on account of its inherent injustice. [Footnote 1: _Laws_, v. ch. 11-13.] Aristotle condemns usury because it is the most extreme and dangerous form of chrematistic acquisition, or the art of making money for its own sake. As we have seen above, in discussing the legitimacy of commerce, buying cheap and selling dear was one form of chrematistic acquisition, which could only be justified by the presence of certain motives; and usury, according to the philosopher, was a still more striking example of the same kind of acquisition, because it consisted in making money from money, which was thus employed for a function different from that for which it had been originally invented. 'Usury is most reasonably detested, as the increase of our fortune arises from the money itself, and not by employing it for the purpose for which it was intended. For it was devised for the sake of exchange, but usury multiplies it. And hence usury has received the name of [Greek: tokos], or produce; for whatever is produced is itself like its parents; and usury is merely money born o
PREV.   NEXT  
|<   107   108   109   110   111   112   113   114   115   116   117   118   119   120   121   122   123   124   125   126   127   128   129   130   131  
132   133   134   135   136   137   138   139   140   141   142   143   144   145   146   147   148   149   150   151   152   153   154   155   156   >>   >|  



Top keywords:

Footnote

 

interest

 

acquisition

 
making
 
chrematistic
 

Justinian

 

Cleary

 

maximum

 
legitimacy
 

discussing


objection
 

account

 

effects

 

probable

 

buying

 

philosophical

 

commerce

 

extreme

 
dangerous
 

Aristotle


condemns

 

injustice

 

condemn

 

content

 

inherent

 

devised

 

exchange

 

multiplies

 

intended

 

purpose


fortune

 

arises

 
employing
 

parents

 

produced

 

received

 

produce

 
increase
 
detested
 

motives


philosopher

 
develop
 

presence

 

justified

 
striking
 
originally
 

invented

 

consisted

 

employed

 

function